Announcement

Collapse
No announcement yet.

IMF: Setting Inflation Target Remains An Effective Tool

Collapse
X
 
  • Filter
  • Time
  • Show
Clear All
new posts

  • IMF: Setting Inflation Target Remains An Effective Tool

    SETTING INFLATION TARGET REMAINS AN EFFECTIVE TOOL

    International Monetary Fund
    http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/survey/so/2011/RES053111A.htm
    May 31 2011

    By Mark Horton, Anna Bordon, and Alina Luca, IMF Middle East and
    Central Asia Department and Douglas Laxton, IMF Research Department

    Central bankers discuss experiences with inflation-forecast targeting
    Participating countries face serious post-crisis challenges, fragile
    recovery Change in mindset, clear communications, better analytical
    tools are required

    Adopting an inflation-forecast targeting regime can help reduce
    economic uncertainty and the severity of boom-and-bust cycles--two
    benefits that were borne out in several countries during the recent
    crisis and the subsequent rise in food and fuel prices, economists
    said at a seminar in Armenia.

    But for this method to succeed, policymakers must change their mindset
    and embrace flexible exchange rates, communicate more clearly, and
    strengthen their analytical tools.

    These were some of the key conclusions of central bankers and other
    policymakers from emerging Europe, Central Asia, and the Caucasus
    as they gathered in late April to share their experiences with
    inflation-forecast targeting. The eight-day workshop--held in Yerevan
    and Tshakhkadzor, Armenia--was jointly organized by the International
    Monetary Fund, the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development,
    and the Central Bank of Armenia.

    As with traditional inflation targeting, a central bank using
    inflation-forecast targeting adopts a formal, public target for the
    inflation rate and then attempts to steer actual inflation toward the
    target through the use of interest rate changes and other monetary
    instruments.

    However, this type of targeting involves greater degree of transparency
    and communication of monetary policy decisions, centered on publication
    of a forecast for inflation and interest rates (or assumptions
    underpinning the forecast). At times, the inflation forecast may
    represent an intermediate target that the central bank aims to bring
    back to the formal target over time.

    Other hallmarks of the regime--which evolved from traditional inflation
    targeting--are public discussion of the forecasts, communicating the
    reasons for missed targets, and explaining how policy will act to
    return inflation to the target in the future.

    Difficult times

    Central banks in emerging Europe, Central Asia and the Caucasus face
    difficult challenges. The recovery is fragile, some economies are
    highly dollarized, financial sectors remain underdeveloped and in
    some cases impaired from the crisis, and fiscal space is limited. The
    region has been confronted by volatile capital flows and a large
    increase in food and fuel prices--a phenomenon that is strongly felt
    by consumers in these countries, who spend a large proportion of
    their income on food.

    These challenges--particularly the emerging threat of
    inflation--provided the impetus for the conference.

    Conference organizers Douglas Laxton of the IMF's Research Department,
    Mark Horton of the IMF's Middle East and Central Asia Department,
    and Ashot Lazarian of the Central Bank of Armenia noted that, where
    flexible inflation-forecast targeting has been applied seriously,
    it has been beneficial in keeping inflation down and anchoring
    longer-term inflation expectations. (In such circumstances, long-run
    market views on inflation are not sensitive to the daily news, a
    sign that the public has confidence that the central bank will keep
    inflation under control over time.)

    Countries that have adopted inflation-forecast targeting chose it in
    most cases because previous monetary policy frameworks had failed
    to maintain low and stable inflation. In those countries, price
    stability has become accepted as the best contribution that monetary
    policy can make to improving the performance of the economy. Greater
    transparency, integral to inflation-forecast targeting, was also seen
    as fully consistent with ongoing moves toward good governance.

    Three basic elements

    Andy Berg of the IMF's Research Department described the three
    key elements of inflation-forecast targeting: a quantitative
    inflation target, an inflation forecast that plays a central role in
    decision-making, and transparency and accountability. Central bankers
    must have clear objectives and sufficient capacity and independence
    to provide these key elements, he stressed.

    Most countries that adopt inflation-forecast targeting do not have
    all these elements in place at the outset, but in almost all cases,
    their modeling and forecasting capability, transparency and policy
    communication, and exchange rate flexibility have improved over time.

    Successful inflation-forecast targeting also requires a change
    in mindset--policymakers must accept the notion that achieving
    low inflation is the primary objective of monetary policy (while
    minimizing the variability of movements in the real economy in the
    course of achieving and maintaining the target rate of inflation), that
    central bank instrument independence is of paramount importance, and
    that fiscal policy concerns cannot dominate monetary policy choices.

    Range of experiences

    New adopters of inflation-forecast targeting are benefiting from the
    success of the pioneers. The Czech Republic was the first transition
    country to introduce it in 1997. ZdenÄ~[k Tůma, a former Czech
    National Bank Governor, explained that this new regime was challenging
    at first because of the disruptions of frequent shocks and volatile
    capital flows.

    Júlia Király of the Bank of Hungary recounted her country's early
    experience, noting that the regime was not consistent with the exchange
    rate band Hungary had in place during 2001-08. The band prevented
    necessary currency appreciation--a key channel for disinflation (a
    slowing of the rate of inflation). This, combined with difficulty in
    assessing the cyclical position of the economy and large household
    currency mismatches, limited the authorities' ability to bring
    inflation down and anchor long-term inflation expectations.

    Bojan Markovic reviewed challenges faced by the Bank of Serbia,
    including a highly euroized economy (that is, the euro is widely used
    for transactions and savings) and high food and headline inflation
    volatility. In such circumstances, he said, a strong and rapid
    policy response in response to shocks is needed to anchor inflation
    expectations. Also, macro-prudential policy instruments are useful
    in complementing conventional monetary policy instruments, and if
    applied carefully, can improve the effectiveness and credibility of
    inflation-forecast targeting regimes.

    The Central Bank of Armenia's Nerses Yeritsyan described the host
    country's 2006 shift to implicit inflation-forecast targeting (in
    other words, targeting a certain level of inflation but not announcing
    the level publicly) as targeting of the money supply became less and
    less reliable. The authorities faced a number of challenges--high
    dollarization; relatively weak linkages between changes in the central
    bank's policy interest rate and changes in other interest rates, in
    economic activity, and in the rate of inflation; shallow financial
    markets; and a difficult fiscal situation.

    After some success, they are now aiming at full-fledged
    inflation-forecast targeting with reforms to better control liquidity
    and to improve communications, as well as introducing indexed
    bonds, and moving decisively away from smoothing the exchange rate
    to anchoring inflation expectations through a more comprehensive
    application of inflation-forecast targeting.

    Change in mindset needed

    ZdenÄ~[k Tůma noted that inflation-forecast targeting requires a
    change in mindset, as the central bank must adopt a flexible exchange
    rate regime. Central banks should also get over their fear of not
    hitting near-term targets and accept the fact that targets will
    sometimes be missed.

    But it is crucial that they continually explain publicly how policy
    will act to return inflation to the target in the future, and publish
    the new inflation and policy interest rate forecasts consistent
    with inflation returning to target. It is equally important for
    central banks to abandon the view that less communication is better
    (common when the exchange rate is fixed) and move toward more
    open communication, which will help align expectations with policy
    objectives.

    The bottom line is that inflation-forecast targeting is as much
    about missing the targets over the short term as hitting them, and
    policymakers should not feel compelled to do "whatever it takes"
    to meet targets on a period-by-period basis. This attitude could be
    very costly and counterproductive for the both economy and for the
    central bank's credibility.

    According to Tůma, inflation-forecast targeting puts an end to
    "real-time attention" on the exchange rate and replaces it with
    painstaking analysis of the economy. The switch enables decision-making
    under uncertainty. Policy moves away from responding to every market
    movement to reacting to expected movements in economic variables,
    relying on a model that forecasts inflation paths with internally
    consistent and time-consistent updates of interest rate trajectories.

    Guy Meredith, a former Bank of Canada and IMF official, noted that
    countries that adopt such a regime need to learn to live with exchange
    rate volatility. While not ignoring movements of the exchange rate,
    responses under inflation-forecast targeting should also not unduly
    limit them. Policymakers could also implement strategies to weaken
    incentives to build up excessive foreign exchange exposures.

    On the question of whether exchange rate volatility should be resisted
    more in dollarized economies, Archil Mestvirishivili of the National
    Bank of Georgia pointed out that exchange rate volatility can help
    reduce dollarization over time by educating the public about the
    risks of foreign exchange holdings and borrowing.

    Communication is crucial

    Inflation-forecast targeting requires greater transparency through
    various forms of communication. Central banks need to communicate
    that they cannot--and are not trying to--determine the inflation
    rate over the short run. Rather, they are focusing on taking policy
    actions to return the rate of inflation to its target over the medium
    run following shocks to the economy and thereby anchoring long-term
    inflation expectations.

    Former Bank of Canada official Jack Selody explained that
    communications generally improve over time, as central banks repeatedly
    explain how their monetary policy actions will bring inflation back
    to target along a forecast path and as they educate the market about
    the implications of uncertainty.

    Selody also highlighted a major difficulty of inflation-forecast
    targeting: striking the right balance between flexibility and
    credibility. Flexibility in achieving the inflation objective (for
    example, a gradual return to the target following a shock) may well
    enhance credibility, but flexibility that temporarily abandons the
    target in favor of other objectives will be costly in terms of lost
    credibility.

    In the early stages of inflation-forecast targeting, foregoing
    flexibility (in the sense of returning inflation to its target more
    quickly than might otherwise be optimal) may help earn credibility.

    Good communication of the reasons for, the benefits of, and the limits
    to flexibility is central to maintaining credibility.

    Modeling and forecasting staff from 14 central banks in the region
    stayed on for a week of training in the analytical tools needed to
    support full-fledged inflation-forecast targeting frameworks.

Working...
X